Lenin the liberal? A reply to Chris Cutrone
David Adam
Platypus Review 40 | October 2011
CHRIS CUTRONEâS RECENT ARTICLE âLeninâs Liberalismâ (Platypus Review #36) claims that Leninâs politics are distorted when characterized as a pure opposition to bourgeois conditions. In fact, he suggests that Lenin insisted on âthe mediation of politics in societyâ even after the creation of a âworkersâ state,â demonstrating a liberal desire to preserve certain features of bourgeois society. His use of Leninâs theory regarding the continuation of âbourgeois rightâ betrays an inattention to the context of Leninâs remarks, and the notion that Lenin applied a liberal perspective to the question of working class political power does not ring true. The essay seems to conjure an ideal Lenin that can more readily be used as a reference point for contemporary Marxism. Cutroneâs claim that Lenin sought to âfulfill the desiderata of bourgeois societyâ rests on a strategy of non-confrontation with the messy historical details of Leninâs relationship with liberal political ideals.
In this response, I will appraise the content of Leninâs liberalism in more concrete terms, particularly the claim that Leninâs notion of the persistence of âbourgeois rightâ in socialism undergirds his belief in âan articulated non-identity of state, political parties, and other voluntary civil society institutions such as labor unions.â We will see that the notion of âbourgeois rightâ is not evidence of a liberal perspective in Lenin, and that within Leninâs discussion of socialist transition it supports an understanding of the state as an economic actor, not as the site of political mediation. Â Then I will show how the liberalism ascribed to Lenin is largely mythical in light of his political practice in the context of a so-called âworkersâ state.â In the early Soviet state, the imperatives of economic construction and the management of power led Lenin both to a more radical rejection of liberal values in politics, as well as a reinforcement of bourgeois relations in production. While I reject Cutroneâs expansive interpretation of Leninâs liberalism, there are other, more restrictive reasons for calling Lenin a liberal.
âBourgeois Rightâ and socialist transformation
Lenin elaborates the idea of âbourgeois rightâ in The State and Revolution (1917), while discussing Marxâs Critique of the Gotha Program [1875], where the phrase âbourgeois rightâ is used. In that text, Marx describes two phases of communist society that follow the transformation of capitalism into communism. The first phase of communist society is characterized as one that has just emerged out of capitalism, while the âhigher phaseâ develops on the basis of communist society itself.
The distinguishing feature of the first phase of communism is that individual consumption is linked to labor expended in production. The individual producer âgets from society a receipt that he has contributed such and such an amount of labor (after a deduction of labor for common reserves) and withdraws from societyâs stores of the means of consumption an equal amount costed in labor terms.â[1]Â This is a communist society, a âco-operatively organized society based on common ownership in the means of production,â in which the labor expended on products does not appear âas the value of these products.â[2]Â Nonetheless, insofar as the common standard of labor expenditure is applied to all, the equal right of the producers âis stillâat least in principleâa bourgeois right,â according to Marx.[3]Â It is a bourgeois right because only in bourgeois society does the notion of abstract human equality, and thus the application of a common standard of justice to all people, become prevalent. In the context of Marxâs text, however, the notion of âbourgeois rightâ has little connection with the mediation of politics in society.
Marx writes of the âlimited horizon of bourgeois right,â and describes how equal right on the basis of labor leads to inequalities due to the different needs and abilities of the producers.[4]Â Lenin describes this âequal rightâ as âa violation of equality and an injustice.â[5]Â He describes how communist society âis compelled to abolish at first only the âinjusticeâ of the means of production seized by individuals,â and is unable âto eliminate the other injustice, which consists in the distribution of consumer goods âaccording to the amount of labor performedâ (and not according to needs).â[6]Â It is worth noting that the distribution of consumer goods âaccording to the amount of labor performedâ is not a feature of capitalism, as Lenin implies. In a capitalist society, workers sell their labor-power in exchange for wages. The wages they receive, and thus the consumer goods they are able to acquire, do not have a direct connection with the amount of labor they perform, which would be the case in Marxâs conception of the first phase of communism. Instead of an exchange of commodities, as in capitalism, the first phase of communism features a conscious social organization of production, replacing the capitalist opposition between the producers and the conditions of production. As Marx wrote in Capital, in such a society âthe social relations of the individual producers, both towards their labor and the products of their labor, are here transparent in their simplicity, in production as well as in distribution.â[7]Â Lenin does not clearly distinguish the relation of the producers to their labor and their products in capitalism from this relation in socialism. Lenin therefore imagines that the concept of âbourgeois rightâ describes a determinate social relation that persists throughout the change from capitalism to communism.
After describing the first phase of communism in terms of the notion of âbourgeois right,â Lenin deduces from this notion that âthere still remains the need for a state, which, while safeguarding the common ownership of the means of production, would safeguard equality in labor and in the distribution of products.â[8]Â The continued existence of economic functions for a political state separate from society as a whole reveals that economic relations have not completely been brought under the collective control of the producers. Lenin further describes this state as a âbourgeois state, without the bourgeoisie.â[9]Â Leninâs assertion of the necessity for a bourgeois state does not follow from Marxâs argument in The Critique of the Gotha Program. Marx had long identified the state as an expression of class rule, and the existence of a state in a communist society is incompatible with Marxâs basic framework. Paresh Chattopadhyay has pointed to the strangeness of Leninâs conclusion:
Inasmuch as the first phase [of communism] is inaugurated only after the transition period has come to an endâalong with the proletarian dictatorship which had arisen on the ruins of the bourgeois stateâthe existence of the bourgeois state in this phase, then, would imply that, in the absence of the bourgeoisie (by Marxâs as well as Leninâs assumption), the workers themselves recreate the bourgeois state (however partially) after having abolished their own. Does not this sound a little far-fetched, to say the least?[10]
It seems probable that this is not quite what Lenin had in mind. It seems likely that the âproletarian stateâ associated by Lenin with proletarian dictatorship was not clearly distinguished from the âbourgeois state without the bourgeoisie.â
For Lenin, the economic revolution presided over by the âarmed workersâ (proletarian dictatorship) consists of nationalization of industry, such that the state continues to persist as an economic actor and employer during the first phase of communism. From this, it seems inconsistent in the extreme to imagine that, after the workersâ state successfully nationalizes industry, the state withers away and is replaced by a bourgeois state that manages that same industry. It seems more consistent to interpret Lenin as describing the same state as both a âproletarian stateâ and as a âbourgeois state without the bourgeoisieâ in different contexts. That Lenin uses Engelsâs description of the Paris Commune as âno longer a state in the proper sense of the wordâ to refer to the state in the first phase of communism appears to support this interpretation.[11]
In The State and Revolution, Leninâs notion of a bourgeois state without the bourgeoisie is central to his understanding of socialist transition. While Leninâs discussion of the Paris Commune does focus on the theme of democracy and political emancipation, the discussion of âbourgeois rightâ grounds an understanding of the state as an economic actor in the transition period. The latter is all the more important in light of Leninâs politics in the Soviet âworkersâ state.â
Lenin understands the first phase of communism as necessitating the transformation of all workers into âhired employees of the state.â[12]Â He writes, âthe whole of society will have become a single office and a single factory, with equality of labor and pay.â[13]Â His notion of a bourgeois state resting upon âbourgeois rightâ elides the difference between the capitalist organization of production and the socialist organization of production. While Marx assumed a fundamentally different organization of production from capitalism, and then discusses a parallel with capitalismââbourgeois rightââLenin deduces the existence of the main organizer of productionâthe stateâfrom the abstract level of right. While the producers must co-operatively administer production for Marx to talk about communism, Lenin writes that, during this socialist phase (he describes the first phase of communism as socialism), all workers are to learn to âindependently administer social production.â[14]Â After this is accomplished, âthe door will be thrown wide open for the transition from the first phase of communist society to its higher phase, and with it to the complete withering away of the state.â[15]Â Essentially, Lenin conflates the revolutionary transformation of capitalism into communism with the transition to what Marx had called âthe higher phase of communist society.â
The transformation of capitalism into communism, which for Marx must take place before we can speak of a new society, finds its equivalent for Lenin in something that occurs âovernight,â namely the replacing of the economic control of capitalists and bureaucrats with that of the âarmed workers.â[16]Â While Lenin writes of a long transitional period, the introduction of socialist economic planning is actually surprisingly swift, insofar as it merely consists of replacing the capitalists and bureaucrats. In a text written within months of The State and Revolution, Lenin explains that âa single State Bankâ will constitute
as much as nine-tenths of the socialist apparatusâŠWe can âlay hold ofâ and âset in motionâ this âstate apparatusâ (which is not fully a state apparatus under capitalism, but which will be so with us, under socialism) at one stroke, by a single decree, because the actual work of book-keeping, control, registering, accounting and counting is performed by employees, the majority of whom themselves lead a proletarian or semi-proletarian existence.[17]
This socialist apparatus, with a bourgeois state run by armed workers at its center, extends a certain factory discipline to the whole of society.[18]Â Leninâs understanding of âbourgeois rightâ leads him to see the âbourgeois state without the bourgeoisieâ as an enforcer of equality and equal rights in production. It does not, contra Cutrone, lead to a liberal political perspective, or any notion of independent political parties whatsoever, despite the fact that the phrase âbourgeois rightâ sounds exceedingly liberal. Since it is the workersâ state that ends up enforcing âbourgeois right,â the liberal virtues of this state depend fundamentally on how the workersâ state is conceived. In The State and Revolution, Lenin supports the idea of a vanguard party assuming power and âdirecting and organizing the new system.â[19]Â By Cutroneâs standards, this vision is discontinuous with the liberal tradition: he claims that, âthe articulation of [political parties] with political power struck classical liberal thinkers as particularly dangerous.â[20]Â If such a vanguard party enforces something called âbourgeois right,â this does not make it any more liberal.
The practice of politics
Cutrone claims that Lenin supported the non-identity of party and state, and states that Leninâs party was meant to be âone party among many parties.â He wants to portray Leninâs model of the party as a more liberal, less authoritarian formation than a social-democratic âparty of the whole class,â but he is unable to offer a compelling argument. For at the Eleventh Party Congress in March 1922, Lenin identifies the party with the state: â⊠the state is the workers, the advanced section of the workers, the vanguard. We are the state.â[21] This is hardly an isolated comment, and it reflected the political realityâthe dictatorship of one party, which Lenin had defended for years. As he said in July 1919,
When we are reproached with having established a dictatorship of one party and, as you have heard, a united socialist front is proposed, we say, âYes, it is a dictatorship of one party! This is what we stand for and we shall not shift from that position because it is the party that has won, in the course of decades, the position of vanguard of the entire factory and industrial proletariat. This party had won that position even before the revolution of 1905. It is the party that was at the head of the workers in 1905 and which since thenâeven at the time of the reaction after 1905 when the working-class movement was rehabilitated with such difficulty under the Stolypin Dumaâmerged with the working class and it alone could lead that class to a profound, fundamental change in the old society.â[22]
Not only did Lenin believe that the Bolshevik party in some sense âmerged with the working class,â but he also berated the German Left for the âmost incredibly and hopelessly muddled thinkingâ in distinguishing between party dictatorship and class dictatorship.[23]
Lenin often tried to justify a lack of democratic rights by identifying such rights with bourgeois society, as if they are merely identical with the freedom of capital.[24]Â Rather than try to preserve âthe possibility of politics within the working class,â as Cutrone imagines, Lenin refused to support freedom of the press for opposition parties.[25]Â Within the party, the ban on factions moved by Lenin at the Tenth Party Congress in March 1921 helped contribute to a decidedly illiberal party culture.[26]Â One could argue that Leninâs approach was the only realistic one in Russia at the time or surmise that freedom of the press and free elections to the Soviets would have swept the Bolsheviks from power and empowered the forces of reaction. Lenin, howeverâand this is a crucial pointâdid not seem to see the fusion of party and state (inevitable or not) as problematic with respect to the building of socialism. The justice of this fusion was predicated on the assumed identity of interest of the masses and the Bolshevik Party, a party described by Lenin as having âas far back as 1905 and even earlier merged with the entire revolutionary proletariat.â[27]
With regard to the trade unions, while Lenin did not identify them with the state or the party, he was also not a principled champion of their independence. In January 1918, for example, Lenin called for the expulsion from the Party of the Bolshevik trade unionist A. Lozovsky, who, according to Lenin, refused âto accept the idea that it is the duty of the trade unions to take upon themselves state functions.â[28]Â In âLeft-Wingâ CommunismâAn Infantile Disorder, Lenin denounced as one of the âcounter-revolutionary machinationsâ of the Mensheviks their defense of trade union independence from the state, despite the fact that Cutrone cites this text as exemplifying some sort of liberal approach.[29]
The trade union debate of 1920-1921, mentioned by Cutrone, highlighted Leninâs opposition to the complete subsumption of the unions in the state. This should not be seen, however, as a principled rejection of his previous positions, but rather as a response to a changing political situation. Lenin came to characterize the function of the trade unions as contradictory: as âparticipants in the exercise of state powerâ the unions would need coercion, but in their key educative role, persuasion had to be their mode of operating.[30]Â Lenin had accused Trotsky of ignoring the latter function of trade unions. Unlike Trotsky, Lenin acknowledged the need for the trade unions to play a mediating role between the workers and the state. Since Lenin saw the state as fundamentally representing working class interests, workersâ struggles could only be justified as a correction of âbureaucratic distortions of the proletarian state.â[31]Â Leninâs overall view of the unions was instrumental rather than liberal or democratic:
Just as the very best factory, with the very best motors and first-class machines, will be forced to remain idle if the transmission belts from the motors to the machines are damaged, so our work of socialist construction must meet with inevitable disaster if the trade unionsâthe transmission belts from the Communist Party to the massesâare badly fitted or function badly.â[32]
While the trade unions were supposed to play an educational role, the party was to have authority in industry until the time when the workers become capable of self-management. During the trade union debate, Lenin stigmatized the âsyndicalist deviationâ of those who wanted the unions to take on managerial functions. âWhy have a Party,â Lenin asked in January 1921, if industrial management is to be left to the trade unions, ânine-tenths of whose members are non-Party workers?â[33]Â It is here, in the relation between the workers and their workâand not in regard to the function of a political partyâthat Lenin could be said to be a liberal.
With regard to the socialist transformation of industry, Lenin argued that the question of collective or individual and dictatorial administration of industry has nothing to do with which class is the ruling class. Against opposition from the left, Lenin appealed to the example of liberal capitalism in a March 1920 speech:
You know that one of the points in dispute, one that arouses the liveliest discussion both in the press and at meetings, is that of one-man management or corporate management. I think that the preference for corporate management not infrequently betrays an inadequate comprehension of the tasks confronting the Republic; what is more, it often testifies to insufficient class-consciousness. When I reflect on this question, I always feel like saying that the workers have not yet learned enough from the bourgeoisieâŠ.Look how the bourgeoisie administer the state; how they have organized the bourgeois class. In the old days, could you have found anyone who shared the views of the bourgeoisie and was their loyal defender, and yet argued that individual authority is incompatible with the administration of the state? If there had been such a blockhead among the bourgeoisie he would have been laughed to scorn by his own class fellows, and would not have been allowed to talk or hold forth at any important meeting of capitalists and bourgeois. They would have asked him what the question of administration through one person or through a corporate body had to do with the question of class. The shrewdest and richest bourgeoisies are the British and American; the British are in many respects more experienced, and they know how to rule better than the Americans. And do they not furnish us with examples of maximum individual dictatorship, of maximum speed in administration, and yet they keep the power fully and entirely in the hands of their own class?[34]
In a December 1920 speech on the trade union question, Lenin made a decidedly liberal argument as well, denouncing the slogan of âindustrial democracyâ: âDemocracy is a category proper only to the political sphere,â he insisted.[35]Â The liberal assumption is that democracy is rightfully restricted to the sphere of politics, while the workplace is governed by purely economic imperatives.
Leninâs liberalism, to the extent that it exists after the October Revolution, is not the sort that Cutrone imagines. On the basis of an understanding of socialist transformation as nationalization, Lenin was able to reconcile the task of economic development on the backs of the workers with the idea of proletarian dictatorship. In this theoretical universe, an incredible amount of weight was put on the correct politics of the ruling party, the minority that was actually implementing this proletarian dictatorship. In this way, a certain preservation of bourgeois conditions was coupled with a decidedly illiberal narrative regarding the just dictatorship of a party that had âmergedâ with the masses. |P
[1]. Karl Marx, âCritique of the Gotha Program,â in Later Political Writings (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2010), 213. Available online at <http://marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1875/gotha/index.htm>.
[2]. Ibid., 213.
[3]. Ibid., 214.
[4]. Ibid., 214.
[5]. V. I. Lenin, "The State and Revolution," in The Lenin Anthology, Robert C. Tucker (New York: Norton, 1975), 376. Available online at <http://marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1917/staterev/index.htm>.
[6]. Ibid., 377.
[7]. Karl Marx, Capital: A Critique of Political Economy (London: Penguin, 1990), 1: 172. Available online at <http://marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/index.htm>.
[8]. Lenin, The State and Revolution, 378.
[9]. Ibid., 381.
[10]. Paresh Chattopadhyay, âThe Economic Content of Socialism: Marx vs. Lenin,â Review of Radical Political Economics 24, no. 3&4 (1992), 108.
[11]. Lenin, The State and Revolution, 383.
[12]. Ibid.
[13]. Ibid.
[14]. Ibid.
[15]. Ibid., 384.
[16]. Ibid., 382.
[17]. Lenin, âCan the Bolsheviks Retain State Power?â in The Lenin Anthology, 401. Available online at <http://marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1917/oct/01.htm>.
[18]. Lenin, The State and Revolution, 383.
[19]. Ibid., 328.
[20]. Chris Cutrone, âLeninâs Liberalism,â Platypus Review #36 (June 2011), available online at <http://platypus1917.org/2011/06/01/lenin%E2%80%99s-liberalism/>.
[21]. V. I. Lenin, âPolitical Report of the Central Committee of the R.C.P. (B.),â in Collected Works, vol. 33 (Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1966), 278. Available online at <http://marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1922/mar/27.htm>.
[22]. V. I. Lenin, âSpeech at the First All-Russia Congress of Workers in Education and Socialist Culture,â in Collected Works, vol. 29 (Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1965), 535. Available online at <http://marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1919/aug/05.htm>.
[23]. Lenin, âLeft-Wingâ CommunismâAn Infantile Disorder, in The Lenin Anthology, 567. Available online at <http://marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1920/lwc/index.htm>.
[24]. Lenin, âSpeech at the First All-Russia Congress of Workers in Education and Socialist Culture,â 534.
[25]. Simon Pirani, The Russian Revolution in Retreat, 1920-24: Soviet Workers and the New Communist Elite (New York: Routledge, 2008), 100-101.
[26]. Ibid., 89.
[27]. V. I. Lenin, âLetter to the Workers and Peasants Apropos of the Victory Over Kolchak,â in Collected Works, vol. 29 (Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1965), 559. Available online at <http://marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1919/aug/24.htm>.
[28]. Hal Draper, The âDictatorship of the Proletariatâ from Marx to Lenin (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1987), 100-101.
[29]. Lenin, âLeft-Wingâ CommunismâAn Infantile Disorder, 573.
[30]. V. I. Lenin, âThe Role and Functions of the Trade Unions Under the New Economic Policy,â in Collected Works, vol. 33 (Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1966), 193. Available online at <http://marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1921/dec/30.htm>.
[31]. Ibid., 187.
[32]. Ibid., 192.
[33]. V. I. Lenin, âThe Party Crisis,â in Collected Works, vol. 32 (Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1965), 50. Available online at <http://marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1921/jan/19.htm>.
[34]. V. I. Lenin, âSpeech Delivered at the Third All-Russia Congress of Water Transport Workers,â in Collected Works, vol. 30 (Moscow: Progress Publishers 1977), 426-427. Available online at <http://marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1920/mar/15.htm>.
[35]. Lenin, âThe Trade Unions, the Present Situation and Trotskyâs Mistakes,â in Collected Works, vol. 32 (Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1965), 26. Available online at <http://marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1920/dec/30.htm>.